Adam Smith
Smith
is principally known for his contributions to political economy and moral
philosophy. He was an extremely sensitive man who possessed a strong sense of
right and wrong that guided the way in which he conducted his life. Wealth
of Nations represents a highly critical commentary on mercantilism, the prevailing economic system of
Smith's day. It should be noted that Smith developed an increasingly critical
view of the Christianity of his time, partly because of his personal
experiences with Christianity and surely also due to the critical view of
Christianity that prevailed in the intellectual circles that shaped the
Scottish Enlightenment.
Adam Smith Contribution of Economics
Mercantilism
In
a major section of The Wealth of Nations, Smith attacked mercantilist
trade practices. He insisted that what enriched European nations was not
importing gold and silver but opening up new free-trade markets in the world.
This trade, he wrote, further stimulated the division of labor, expanded the
production of trade goods, and increased “the real revenue and wealth” of all.
However, Smith’s writings span a broad
spectrum of topics ranging from astronomy to the origin of language. Smith
first achieved notoriety because of his Theory of Moral Sentiments
(1759) where he emphasized the important role of sympathy in making moral
decisions. In Moral Sentiments he described a moral compass within
humankind that he referred to as the "impartial spectator." The
"impartial spectator" led the individual to intuit right from
wrong.76) and The Theory of Moral Sentiments (1759) where he emphasized
the important role of sympathy in making moral decisions. In Moral Sentiments
he described a moral compass within humankind that he referred to as the
"impartial spectator." The "impartial spectator" led the
individual to intuit right from wrong. Wealth of Nations represents a highly
critical commentary on mercantilism, the prevailing economic system of Smith's
day. Mercantilism emphasized the maximizing of exports and the minimizing of
imports. In Wealth of Nations Smith argues that everyone benefits from the removal
of tariffs and other barriers to trade. Because of supply and demand,
production will increase as demand increases. This may lead to new employment
opportunities for the workforce and to collateral industries emerging in
response to new demands. Smith makes compelling arguments for the free market
and his economic and moral writings remain relevant today. Wealth of Nations
serves as one of the most elegant explanations for the rapid economic growth
experienced by the United States and other industrial powers in the nineteenth
and twentieth centuries.
In 1763, Smith quit his professorship at Glasgow and tutored the stepson of Charles Townshend, who later became Britain’s treasury minister in the years leading up to the American Revolution. Smith traveled to Paris with his student and met Voltaire and other philosophers involved in the French Enlightenment. Smith also met the leading French economist, Francois Quesnay. Quesnay had devised a system called “Physiocracy” that he believed explained the source of national wealth. He took issue with the popular belief, known as mercantilism that a nation’s wealth was its hoard of gold or silver. Quesnay believed a nation’s wealth came from its farm produce that circulated throughout the land, nourishing everyone. Quesnay’s innovative idea prompted Smith to begin to write his own book on economics.
Though Smith aimed much of his fire at
the 'mercantile system', his argument fell short of the level of analytical
sophistication reached earlier by his friend, David Hume. In the 1760s Hume had
attacked mercantilism by invoking a theory linking the general level of prices
to the quantity of money. The larger the supply of money, he had argued, the
higher the price level was likely to rise; higher prices, in turn, would tend
to make exports less competitive in foreign markets and imports more
competitive in home markets. The mercantilist drive to enlarge the stock of
money would thus be self-defeating; the accumulation of precious metals would
produce effects that would later erode the favorable balance of trade. Hume, of
course, needed another prop to this argument before it could stick; after all,
a convinced mercantilist could reply that appropriate regulations could check a
deterioration in the balance of trade. Hume supplied the needed reinforcement
by insisting that restrictions on trade would be damaging to the national
interest. A country invoking direct controls would be punishing itself by
foregoing the benefits of an international specialization and division of
labor. This line of critique carried more weight than did much of Smith's
attack. His position, in fact, can largely be summarized in the proposition
that government meant restrictions and that restrictions necessarily frustrated
the natural division of labor, the operation of the invisible hand, and the
progress of improvement.
Invisible Hand Theory
"The Wealth of Nations,"
documented industrial development in Europe. While critics note that Smith
didn't invent many of the ideas that he wrote about, he was the first person to
compile and publish them in a format designed to explain them to the average
reader of the day. As a result, he is responsible for popularizing many of the
ideas that underpin the school of thought that became known as classical
economics.
Laissez-faire philosophies, such as
minimizing the role of government intervention and taxation in the free
markets, and the idea that an "invisible hand"
guides supply and demand are among the key ideas Smith's writing is responsible
for promoting. These ideas reflect the concept that each person, by looking out
for him or herself, inadvertently helps to create the best outcome for
all. "It is not from the benevolence of the butcher, the brewer, or the
baker, that we can expect our dinner, but from their regard to their own
interest," Smith wrote.
Adam Smith’s
“Free Market Mechanism”
The following is a simplified version of the economic system Adam Smith
believed would emerge once governments ended their oppressive mercantilist
policies.
1.
A
man builds a cloth-making factory, hires workers, and divides their labor into
many specialized operations. The factory owner is motivated by self-interest,
profit, maybe even greed.
2.
Others,
however, are also building factories to make and sell cloth. They all have to
compete for the money of the buyers whose self- interest is to buy cloth at the
best price.
3.
Buyers
bid up the price of the cloth when the supply of cloth is low and their demand
for it is high. But when there is an oversupply, the buyers can pick and choose
and refuse to purchase high-priced cloth. The factory owners then have to
reduce their prices to attract more buyers. Economists call this the “law of
supply and demand.”
4.
Additional
innovative divisions of labor, maybe brought on by new machinery, motivate
others to invest in more factories. But they must compete to hire more workers.
The “law of supply and demand” applies here, too, and wages go up.
5.
Higher
wages lengthen the lives of workers and their children. The population grows,
which increases the supply of workers. Wages then stop rising. But, soon
another division of labor wave occurs, producing more economic growth and the
need for even more workers. Wages go up again. The cycle repeats itself.
6.
Families
now can afford to buy (demand) more cloth and lots of other products. The
factory owners make more profits. Everybody wins and society as a whole
improves.
7.
The
cloth factory owner never intended to improve society; he just wanted to make
money for himself. But his self-interest, as if “led by an invisible hand,”
resulted in the betterment of all. As Adam Smith himself put it, “By pursuing
his own interest he frequently promotes that of the society more effectively
than when he really intends to promote it.”

Conclusion
The ideas that became associated with Smith not only became
the foundation of the classical school of economics,
but also gained him a place in history as the father of economics. His work
served as the basis for other lines of inquiry into the economics field,
including ideas that built on his work and those that differed. Smith died on
July 19, 1790, but the ideas he promoted live on. In 2007, the Bank
of England placed his image on the £20 note.

No comments:
Post a Comment